WHAT IS THE DIFFERENCE BETWEEN PERCEIVED DEMAND AND MARKET DEMAND?
The demand curve as perceived by a perfectly competitive firm is not the overall market demand curve for that product. However, the firm’s demand curve as perceived by a monopoly is the same as the market demand curve. The reason for the difference is that each perfectly competitive firm perceives the demand for its products in a market that includes many other firms; in effect, the demand curve perceived by a perfectly competitive firm is a tiny slice of the entire market demand curve. In contrast, a monopoly perceives demand for its product in a market where the monopoly is the only producer.
Total Cost and Total Revenue for a Monopolist
Profits for a monopolist can be illustrated with a graph of total revenues and total costs, as shown with the example of the hypothetical HealthPill firm in Figure 9.4. The total cost curve has its typical shape; that is, total costs rise and the curve grows steeper as output increases.To calculate total revenue for a monopolist, start with the demand curve perceived by the monopolist. Table 9.2 shows quantities along the demand curve and the price at each quantity demanded, and then calculates total revenue by multiplying price times quantity at each level of output. (In this example, the output is given as 1, 2, 3, 4, and so on, for the sake of simplicity. If you prefer a dash of greater realism, you can imagine that these output levels and the corresponding prices are measured per 1,000 or 10,000 pills.) As the figure illustrates, total revenue for a monopolist rises, flattens out, and then falls. In this example, total revenue is highest at a quantity of 6 or 7. Clearly, the total revenue for a monopolist is not a straight upward-sloping line, in the way that total revenue was for a perfectly competitive firm. The different total revenue pattern for a monopolist occurs because the quantity that a monopolist chooses to produce affects the market price, which was not true for a perfectly competitive firm. If the monopolist charges a very high price, then quantity demanded drops, and so total revenue is very low. If the monopolist charges a very low price, then, even if quantity demanded is very high, total revenue will not add up to much. At some intermediate level, total revenue will be highest. However, the monopolist is not seeking to maximize revenue, but instead to earn the highest possible profit. Profits are calculated in the final row of the table. In the HealthPill example in Figure 9.4, the highest profit will occur at the quantity where total revenue is the farthest above total cost. Of the choices given in the table, the highest profits occur at an output of 4, where profit is 900.
Table 9.2 Total Costs and Total Revenues of HealthPill Quantity Total Cost Quantity Price Total Revenue Profit = Total Revenue – Total Cost 1 1,500 1 1,200 1,200 –300 2 1,800 2 1,100 2,200 400 3 2,200 3 1,000 3,000 800 4 2,800 4 900 3,600 900 5 3,500 5 800 4,000 700 6 4,200 6 700 4,200 0 7 5,600 7 600 4,200 –1,400 8 7,400 8 500 4,000 –3,400 Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost for a Monopolist
In the real world, a monopolist often does not have enough information to analyze its entire total revenues or total costs curves; after all, the firm does not know exactly what would happen if it were to alter production dramatically. But a monopolist often has fairly reliable information about how changing output by small or moderate amounts will affect its marginal revenues and marginal costs, because it has had experience with such changes over time and because modest changes are easier to extrapolate from current experience. A monopolist can use information on marginal revenue and marginal cost to seek out the profit-maximizing combination of quantity and price. The first four columns of Table 9.3 use the numbers on total cost from the HealthPill example in the previous exhibit and calculate marginal cost and average cost. This monopoly faces a typical U-shaped average cost curve and upward-sloping marginal cost curve, as shown in Figure 9.5. The second four columns of Table 9.3 use the total revenue information from the previous exhibit and calculate marginal revenue. Notice that marginal revenue is zero at a quantity of 7, and turns negative at quantities higher than 7. It may seem counterintuitive that marginal revenue could ever be zero or negative: after all, does an increase in quantity sold not always mean more revenue? For a perfect competitor, each additional unit sold brought a positive marginal revenue, because marginal revenue was equal to the given market price. But a monopolist can sell a larger quantity and see a decline in total revenue. When a monopolist increases sales by one unit, it gains some marginal revenue from selling that extra unit, but also loses some marginal revenue because every other unit must now be sold at a lower price. As the quantity sold becomes higher, the drop in price affects a greater quantity of sales, eventually causing a situation where more sales cause marginal revenue to be negative.
Cost Information | Revenue Information | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Quantity | Total Cost | Marginal Cost | Average Cost | Quantity | Price | Total Revenue | Total Revenue |
1 | 1,500 | 1,500 | 1,500 | 1 | 1,200 | 1,200 | 1,200 |
2 | 1,800 | 300 | 900 | 2 | 1,100 | 2,200 | 1,000 |
3 | 2,200 | 400 | 733 | 3 | 1,000 | 3,000 | 800 |
4 | 2,800 | 600 | 700 | 4 | 900 | 3,600 | 600 |
5 | 3,500 | 700 | 700 | 5 | 800 | 4,000 | 400 |
6 | 4,400 | 900 | 733 | 6 | 700 | 4,200 | 200 |
7 | 5,600 | 1,200 | 800 | 7 | 600 | 4,200 | 0 |
8 | 7,400 | 1,800 | 925 | 8 | 500 | 4,000 | –200 |
If you find it counterintuitive that producing where marginal revenue equals marginal cost will maximize profits, working through the numbers will help.
Step 1. Remember that marginal cost is defined as the change in total cost from producing a small amount of additional output.
Step 2. Note that in Table 9.3 , as output increases from 1 to 2 units, total cost increases from $1500 to $1800. As a result, the marginal cost of the second unit will be:
Step 3. Remember that, similarly, marginal revenue is the change in total revenue from selling a small amount of additional output.
Step 4. Note that in Table 9.3 , as output increases from 1 to 2 units, total revenue increases from $1200 to $2200. As a result, the marginal revenue of the second unit will be:
Quantity | Marginal Revenue | Marginal Cost | Marginal Profit | Total Profit |
---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 1,200 | 1,500 | –300 | –300 |
2 | 1,000 | 300 | 700 | 400 |
3 | 800 | 400 | 400 | 800 |
4 | 600 | 600 | 0 | 800 |
5 | 400 | 700 | –300 | 500 |
6 | 200 | 900 | –700 | –200 |
7 | 0 | 1,200 | –1,200 | –1,400 |
Our Advantages
- Quality Work
- Unlimited Revisions
- Affordable Pricing
- 24/7 Support
- Fast Delivery
Order Now