The upcoming discussion will update you about the difference between monopolistic competition and oligopoly. The traditional categorisation of market structures into purely competitive, monopolistically competitive, oligopolistic and monopolistic is both worthwhile (since static processes are easier to present from a teaching perspective) and dangerous (since the dynamic process of struc­tural change is the main issue facing businesspeople.) The four market models are very valuable since they allow us to describe the behaviour of businesses under a given set of static assumptions. The general theory of pricing postulates a spectrum of market conditions that range from perfect competition at one extreme to pure monopoly on the other. In between, a large number of theoretical market structures are possible, but for convenience, they are divided into two broad classes of imperfect competition: monopolistic competition (which is nearer to perfect competition) and oligopoly (which is nearer to pure monopoly). The main differences between monopolistic competition and oligopoly are the number and size of the firms in the market place; these characteristics also determine the impact of a single firm’s pricing decisions.
ADVERTISEMENTS:
Monopolistic competition is more apt to be found in distributing and retailing, where the market can be divided into many small segments without suffering dis­economies of scale. In contrast, oligopoly is found when economies of scale require that the market be supplied by a few large firms. This condition is normally found in manufacturing, insurance and international banking. In both monopolistic competition and oligopoly markets have groups of products that are close substitutes yet differentiated in some respect in the eyes of the buyer. It is not necessary that the product be physically or chemically different. Manufacturers and sometimes distributors or retailers spend a substantial amount of money to persuade consumers that one brand is somehow different from essentially the same product under a different label. Each firm, of course, has a legal monopoly on its registered trademarks and brand names. Firms may also compete while dealing in the same product by differentiating on some other basis, such as service facilities, credit arrangements and location. For example, two service stations may offer the same brand of petroleum products and essentially the same services, but their different locations make them different and each has a monopoly in its location. In both monopolistic competition and oligopoly competition is perfect rather than impersonal. Each seller is acutely aware of competitors and is constantly striving to out-manoeuvre them in order to gain an advantage. Each seller is also aware that there are two demand curves in the market. One is for the whole market, that is, for the aggregate demand for all products that are close substitutes of each other. The other demand curve represents the firm’s share of the market.
ADVERTISEMENTS:
In Fig. 8 d1d1 = original short-run demand curve d2d2 = demand curve after long-run adjustment MR = original marginal revenue curve. Figure 8 sets forth the theoretical picture of a monopolistically competi­tive industry. Because a monopolistic competitor is only one of numerous firms selling a product which has many close substitutes, the firm’s demand curve (dd) in Fig. 8 is almost horizontal. Monopolistic competition As shown in the figure, the firm can earn excess profits in the short run with a price of P1 and an output of Q1. In the long run, however, the existence of this high profit level is a signal for more firms to enter, for the original firm’s de­mand curve to fall to d2d2, for the price to fall to P2 and for output to settle at Q2. While the seller of egg roll may be able to marginally differentiate his rolls from that of the competitors, the absence of barriers to entry means that other potential competitors will constantly be trying to emulate his success and reduce his pricing power. The analysis set forth in Fig. 9 is that of an oligopolist. It describes a situation of interdependence in which the individual oligopolist faces the kinked demand curve DAB and is un­willing to depart from the current price to P3. If an oligopolist raises his price to P2, he fears that no one will follow and his sales will fall sharply. Oligopoly market model On the other hand, if he lowers his price unilaterally to P3, he fears that everyone else will match his price and he will be worse off. The novelty of the kinked demand curve is that it describes a static equilibrium situation in which no price change will take place.